Chapter-3 Politics of Planned Development -(Detailed Notes)
Political Contestation in Development
Case Study: Orissa’s Iron Ore Development
- Context: Orissa, rich in iron ore, attracted investment for steel plants due to global demand. The state government signed MoUs with steel companies, expecting capital investment and jobs.
- Stakeholders and Interests:
- State Government: Seeks economic growth through industrial investment and job creation.
- Tribal Population: Fears displacement from homes and loss of livelihoods, as iron ore lies in underdeveloped tribal districts.
- Environmentalists: Concerned about pollution from mining and industry.
- Central Government: Worries that blocking industry could deter national investments.
- Conflicts:
- Economic growth vs. tribal displacement.
- Industrial development vs. environmental protection.
- State-level job creation vs. national investment climate.
- Common Ground: All stakeholders desire Orissa’s development, but differ on its meaning (e.g., industrial growth vs. sustainable livelihoods).
- Resolution: Requires balancing interests through political decisions, not just expert advice. Democratic processes, involving people’s representatives, are crucial.
- Broader Questions: What kind of development does Orissa need? Whose needs represent Orissa’s needs?
Role of Democracy
- Development decisions involve trade-offs between social groups and generations, requiring political judgment.
- In a democracy, such decisions should be approved by the public or their representatives, informed by experts (e.g., economists, environmentalists) but not dictated by them.
- Post-independence, India faced similar decisions, bound by a shared vision of economic development, necessitating a coordinated strategy.
Ideas of Development
Contestation Over Development
- Development has varied meanings:
- For an industrialist: Setting up a steel plant for profit.
- For an urban consumer: Access to steel products.
- For an Adivasi: Preservation of land and livelihood.
- These differences lead to contradictions, conflicts, and debates, as seen in Orissa.
Western Model of Modernization
- In the 1950s, development was equated with becoming “modern,” modeled on Western industrialized nations.
- Characteristics of modernization:
- Breakdown of traditional social structures.
- Rise of capitalism and liberalism.
- Emphasis on growth, material progress, and scientific rationality.
- Countries were classified as developed, developing, or underdeveloped based on this model.
Development Models at Independence
- India had two models to choose from:
- Liberal-Capitalist Model: As in Europe and the US, emphasizing free markets.
- Socialist Model: As in the USSR, focusing on state control and redistribution.
- Influences:
- Soviet model was popular due to its economic growth against odds.
- Leaders from the Communist Party, Socialist Party, and Congress (e.g., Nehru) admired aspects of the Soviet model.
- Few supported American-style capitalism.
- National movement’s consensus:
- Rejected the colonial government’s commercial focus.
- Prioritized poverty alleviation and social-economic redistribution as government responsibilities.
- Debates within this consensus:
- Industrialization vs. agricultural development.
- Focus on rural poverty vs. urban growth.
Left vs. Right Ideologies
- Left: Favors state control, regulation, and economic redistribution (e.g., Communist Party, Socialist Party).
- Right: Supports free competition and minimal government intervention (e.g., Swatantra Party).
- Congress Party (1950s-1960s): Centrist, leaning Left due to its adoption of socialist principles, but also pursued liberal policies to encourage private investment.
Planning for Development
Consensus on Planning
- Despite debates, there was agreement that development required government planning, not just private initiatives.
- Global support for planning in the 1940s-1950s:
- Great Depression highlighted market failures.
- Post-war reconstruction in Japan and Germany used planning.
- Soviet Union’s rapid growth demonstrated planning’s effectiveness.
The Bombay Plan (1944)
- A group of leading industrialists (e.g., J.R.D. Tata, G.D. Birla) proposed a planned economy, contrary to assumptions that private sector opposes planning.
- Key features:
- Advocated state-led initiatives in industrial and economic investments.
- Supported state ownership and control of key sectors.
- Significance: Showed broad support for planning across political and economic spectra.
Planning Commission
- Establishment: Set up in March 1950 by a government resolution, not a constitutional body.
- Role: Advisory, with recommendations requiring Union Cabinet approval.
- Leadership: Chaired by the Prime Minister, making it a central machinery for development strategy.
- Mandate: Aligned with Directive Principles of State Policy, aiming to:
- Ensure an adequate means of livelihood for all citizens.
- Distribute resources for the common good.
- Prevent concentration of wealth and production means.
- Five-Year Plans (FYPs):
- Adopted from the Soviet model, FYPs outlined government income and expenditure for five years.
- Allowed long-term economic interventions and prioritization.
Early Initiatives: Five-Year Plans
Overview
- The Planning Commission’s FYPs generated widespread excitement, peaking with the Second FYP (1956) and continuing until the Third FYP (1961).
- By the Fourth FYP (due 1966), enthusiasm waned due to economic crises, leading to a “plan holiday.”
- Despite criticisms, the FYPs laid the foundation for India’s economic development.
First Five-Year Plan (1951-1956)
- Objective: Break the cycle of poverty by raising national income.
- Approach: “Hasten slowly,” as advocated by economist K.N. Raj, to protect democracy from rapid development’s risks.
- Focus: Agrarian sector, addressing Partition’s impact on agriculture.
- Key Investments:
- Large-scale irrigation projects (e.g., Bhakhra Nangal Dam).
- Land reforms to address unequal land distribution, identified as a major obstacle to agricultural growth.
- Savings and Capital:
- Aimed to increase savings to boost investment, as low spending couldn’t be reduced further.
- Low capital stock and high employable population posed challenges.
- Savings rose until the Third FYP but fell short of expectations, declining from the 1960s to early 1970s.
Second Five-Year Plan (1956-1961)
- Objective: Rapid structural transformation through industrialization.
- Leadership: Drafted under P.C. Mahalanobis, emphasizing heavy industries.
- Context: Congress’s Avadi session (1955) declared a “socialist pattern of society” as its goal, reflected in the plan.
- Key Features:
- Heavy industry development (e.g., steel, electricity, railways, machinery, communication).
- Public sector dominance in these industries, supported by growing savings and investment.
- Import tariffs to protect domestic industries, fostering growth in both public and private sectors.
- Significance: Marked a turning point in India’s development by prioritizing industrial growth.
Third Five-Year Plan (1961-1966)
- Approach: Continued the Second FYP’s focus on heavy industries.
- Criticisms:
- “Urban bias” in planning, neglecting rural areas.
- Overemphasis on industry over agriculture, risking food shortages.
- Preference for heavy industries over agriculture-related ones.
Challenges
- Technological Backwardness: Required expensive foreign technology imports, straining foreign exchange reserves.
- Industry vs. Agriculture: Heavy industry focus attracted more investment than agriculture, leading to food scarcity risks.
- Balancing Act: Planners struggled to balance industrial and agricultural priorities.
Achievements and Limitations
Achievements
- First FYP:
- Improved agricultural infrastructure through irrigation and dams.
- Initiated land reforms to address inequality.
- Laid groundwork for economic stability.
- Second and Third FYPs:
- Established a strong industrial base, particularly in heavy industries.
- Protected domestic industries through tariffs, fostering growth.
- Public sector growth in critical sectors like steel and electricity.
- Foundation for Development: Despite challenges, FYPs set the stage for India’s long-term economic growth.
Limitations
- Savings Shortfall: Savings did not rise as expected, limiting investment capacity.
- Food Security Risks: Industrial focus led to agricultural neglect, causing potential food shortages.
- Urban Bias: Planning favored urban industrial growth, marginalizing rural areas.
- Foreign Exchange Strain: Reliance on imported technology drained reserves.
- Economic Crisis: By the mid-1960s, crises (e.g., wars, droughts) led to a “plan holiday” and reduced planning enthusiasm.
Abandonment of the Planning Strategy
- Economic Crises: Mid-1960s crises (e.g., 1962 and 1965 wars, droughts) strained the economy, undermining planning confidence.
- Declining Enthusiasm: Novelty of planning faded by the Fourth FYP, with criticisms of urban bias and agricultural neglect gaining traction.
- Global Shift: Rise of market-oriented policies globally in the 1980s influenced India’s move away from state-led planning.
- Liberalization (1991): Economic reforms shifted focus to market-driven growth, reducing the Planning Commission’s role.
- Legacy: While planning was de-emphasized, the early FYPs’ industrial and agricultural foundations remained critical to India’s growth.
Key Figures
- Jawaharlal Nehru (1889-1964): Prime Minister and Planning Commission Chairperson; advocated socialist-inspired planning.
- P.C. Mahalanobis (1893-1972): Statistician; architect of the Second FYP; pushed for rapid industrialization and public sector dominance.
- K.N. Raj (1914-2010): Economist; contributed to the First FYP; advocated a cautious approach to development.
- Verghese Kurien (1921-2012): Led milk cooperatives, contributing to rural development.
- Charan Singh (1902-1987): Advocated for farmers’ interests and agricultural development.